SACU’s
Great Moral Hazard
Economists love talking about moral
hazards. This is when an action has unintended consequence like insurance causing
people to drive recklessly. Namibia and the other three small states Botswana
Lesotho and Swaziland (BLNS states) which together with South Africa make up
the membership of SACU live under a scheme of sharing customs revenue that
create an exception moral hazard. The moral hazard stems from the fact that the
smaller countries get customs revenue from South Africa that bears no
relationship to what they actually import from outside the Customs Union. That
means that these countries have no interest in collecting customs duties. I frequently
complain to Customs Officers in the BLNS states that that they could collect
millions of dollars more money if they just policed the importing of second hand motor vehicles properly and forced
people to declare proper prices. But several weeks ago a Customs official said
something that clarified the SACU situation. His response was blunt and simple
enough- ‘What do I care?’, he blurted’ If I collect all the money that is owed
to us it all goes to Pretoria and what I get back from Pretoria has no
relationship to what I collected.’
This position is absolutely correct
and it is a classic definition of what
economists call a moral hazard. What the customs official gets back from
Pretoria bears no relationship to what he collects. What is collected into the
SACU pool is largely determined by how much South Africa imports from the rest
of the world because SA is by far the biggest member of SACU and what each SACU
member gets back is based, bizarrely, on what each SACU imports from other SACU
members. But that is just as true of all the members of SACU, even South
Africa. If some 80% of customs revenue goes to the four BLNS states as they are
called then what possible incentive does South Africa have to tighten up on
Customs collection.In effect it creates an incentive to turn a blind eye to the
sort of tax evasion that is so pervasive in international trade today.
But there are worse and yet more
expensive moral hazards imbedded in the SACU customs rebate system. The most expensive for countries like the four
small BLNS states which gets most of the
SACU customs revenue, is the duty rebates which eats a huge part of
the total SACU revenue. The country that use duty rebates the most is South
Africa and the sector that employs them most extensively is the automobile
export industry. How does this work.
Under the terms of the South African Automotive Production and
Development program firms that produce cars in South Africa get all sorts of
financial incentives. The most important are the duty remissions and rebates.
The first is the so-called Vehicle Assembly Allowance whereby manufacturers with a
minimumplant volume of 50 000 vehicles per annum are allowed to import a
percentage of their components duty free (20%- decreasing to 18% over 3 years).
The second is the ‘production incentive’ which is an allowance for duty free import of vehicles or
components, calculated at 55% of value added in the SA supply chain; reducing
to 50% over 5 years. The cost of both all comes from SACU revenues. And how
much? In 2015 the South African Department of Trade and Industry reported to
its parliament that the ‘hypothetical’ loss of customs duty from these two
parts of the program were a staggering ZAR 10 billion.
Why
do the South Africans refer to the losses as ‘hypothetical’? It is because the
South African government knows that most of those losses would have gone to the
citizens of the BLNS, and not to South Africans, who would have otherwise
received some 80% of this loss in customs duty. In short Botswana and Namibia
would be about ZAR3-4 billion richer if they were not paying forPretoria’s subsidies to the automobile
manufacturers.
South
Africa benefits by the 110,000 jobs that this industry createsand represents some 7.2% of South Africa’s GDP.
The South African government knows that
the industry would be as dead as its now defunct Australian counterpart,
if these SACU subsidies were removed. But for South Africa, this is mana from
heaven. It is virtually free money, there is no political pressure from South
Africans and there is no incentive to contain the cost of these programs as it
is the citizens of the BLNS that pay!
This is a perfect example of a moral hazard.
But like the entire SACU customs revenue sharing formula, the rebate scheme is based
on the BLNS subsidizing South African, jobs production and exports. But because
the BLNS states get more in subsidies under the revenue sharing formula than
they pay out for rebates everyone just keeps quiet and accepts the continuation
of this economic absurdity. And so it goes on until one
day someone will pull the plug.
These are the views of Professor
Roman Grynberg and not necessarily those of UNAM where he is employed.
No comments:
Post a Comment